Three Essays on Trade Credit Theory and Empirical Evidence from Agro-food Firms in Africa and United States


Book Description

In a quest to understand the motives for use of trade credit in inter-firm trade, many theories have been put forward. The empirical literature on trade credit are largely focused on understanding firms' motives for use of trade credit, by testing these theories with micro- and macro-level data. Against the background that the extent and motives for use of trade credit in the agro-food industry is less understood, this dissertation extends the frontiers of knowledge on trade credit use by examining trade credit theories and empirical evidence from agro-food firms in Africa and the United States. The dissertation consists of three essays. The first essay examines trade credit contracts, trade credit theories and empirical evidence in support of or otherwise of the theories via review and analysis of the theoretical and empirical trade credit literature. The second essay examines the motives for trade credit supply in the African agro-food manufacturing industry, employing survey data from eight African countries - Burundi, Malawi, Mauritania, Namibia, Nigeria, Senegal, South Sudan and Sudan. Premised on the fact that there are benefits and costs of investing in trade credit, the third essay examines investment in trade credit and firm profitability, using a panel of listed agro-food firms in the United States for the period 2001-2014. The review in essay one revealed a high use of trade credit in inter-firm trade, with variations across countries and industries. It is revealed that trade credit contracts are simple in nature and factors such as the shortness of credit periods, frequency of transactions, close proximity and interaction between suppliers and customers, and effective informal enforcement mechanisms may account for the simplified nature of trade credit contracts. However, the use of trade credit is a multidimensional phenomenon, driven by varied yet interconnected motives, thus making it complex to put forward a single theory to explain the use of trade credit in interfirm trade. Contrary to a long-held notion that trade credit is expensive relative to bank credit, evidence from the empirical literature suggests the opposite. In general, there is more empirical support for the theories of trade credit. The empirical results show a high participation of agro-food firms in trade credit activity in African countries and the United States. While within-industry variability in trade credit activity is not statistically significant in the African agro-food industry, there is significant within-industry variability in the United States. However, there is statistically significant variability in trade credit activity across agro-food firms in the African countries studied. The empirical results from essay two show that the level of trade credit supply increases with manager experience, degree of product diversification, overdraft availability from banks, trade credit from input suppliers and location in capital city. The results provide evidence in support of financing (particularly liquidity and redistribution) and commercial (particularly marketing and quality guarantee) theories of trade credit. Essay three found evidence of a non-linear (inverted U) relationship between trade credit investment and firm profitability, reflecting benefits and costs of trade credit investment. This finding suggest that agro-food firms should be guided by benefit-costs off in their trade credit investment decisions. The study found the threshold of trade credit investment beyond which the relationship between trade credit investment and firm profitability transition from positive to negative. In general, the empirical results show that trade credit is an important source of short-term financing for agro-food firms in African countries and the United States, and should be facilitated through policy.







Three Essays in International Economics


Book Description

Chapter 1: This paper contributes to a growing literature on the effects of credit constraints on international trade, and an existing body of literature on the exporting advantage of multinational firms. Using 2013 data from Estonian and Hungarian exporting firms, I find that traditional measures of credit constraints (cash flows, debt to sales ratio, and tangible asset share) have a significant negative effect on the intensive margin of international trade, and being a multinational affiliate has a positive effect on trade. Multinational affiliates export nearly twice as much as domestic firms. I find no strong evidence that multinational affiliates are less credit constrained than domestic firms conditional on firms already exporting. Therefore, any differences between the two types of firms appear on the extensive margin of trade or in domestic activities. Estonia and Hungary are relatively recent EU members that experienced an influx of foreign investment during their transition periods in the 1990s. Therefore, these results provide useful information for studying the long-term benefits of EU accession and foreign investment in transition economies.Chapter 2: This paper analyzes the impact of multinational banking and multinational ownership on the performance of exporting Central European firms. Using a panel of Hungarian, Croatian, and Estonian exporters, I find that controlling for a firm's borrowing behavior leads to a 12.5% reduction in the coefficient on multinational status. Such a non-trivial amount indicates that the "multinational advantage" in export revenue falls from 122% to 102%. This outcome is strongest for Hungarian firms and weakest for Croatian firms, indicating a long-run benefit to increases in foreign banking among recent EU members. Additionally, I find that the Hungarian government's effort to increase domestic banking presence by purchasing two major multinational banks, MKB and Budapest Bank, led to a $270,000 decrease in loans among domestically owned exporters. However, this purchase had no effect on the loans of multinational affiliates. These results provide evidence that multinational affiliates are better able to smooth their borrowing behavior in the presence of a tumultuous banking sector, and that the firms most affected by anti-global banking policies are smaller, locally owned firms. Chapter 3: In 2014, the Austrian bank Hypo Group Alpe Adria went bankrupt and was purchased and rebranded as Addiko bank. The bank was purchased by the American banking group Advent International, and the European Bank for Reconstruction and Development (EBRD), an international organization that serves as an investment bank in former transition economies. Their primary goal is to assist European transition countries in establishing or enriching a market-based economy. In this paper, I explore how this "bailout" of Addiko Bank by an international organization affected exporting firms in Croatia. Specifically, I investigate whether there was a positive effect on firm performance, therefore justifying the need for intervention by an international financial institution. I find that the turnover of Addiko bank led to a $260,000 decrease in loans taken out by firms. However, this effect seems to occur immediately after the turnover, and vanishes over time. Additionally, I find no effect on the export revenue, and total revenue of firms, and a small increase in the domestic revenue amongst the firms. These results indicate that after an initial period of turmoil, the intervention by EBRD and Advent International had no lasting negative (and perhaps slightly positive) effects on firm outcomes.




Essays on International Trade, Capital Flows and Financial Frictions


Book Description

Two particular concerns in international economics motivate this research: I. How are real and financial activities related to each other in a globalized economy? II. What role do financial frictions play in this relationship ? Three essays look at these questions from different perspectives. The first chapter, in collaboration with Jean-Charles Bricongne and SebastianFranco-Bedoya, revises the old question on the relation between FDI and exports on French firms, where theory seems to be at odds with empirical findings. Most FDI and most trade take place between rich markets, where the horizontal investment type is expected to happen. In this sense, empirical studies have almost invariably found a complementarity relation while standard Horizontal FDI models predict substitutability between FDI and exports given the proximity-concentration trade-off. [...]The second chapter empirically examines how external financial needs measured at the sector level- and financial development at the country level interact to shape the aggregate marginal product of capital of a country (MPK) and its foreign direct investment inflows (FDI). First, using new available data we construct annual aggregate MPK for 50 developing and developed countries during 1995-2008; we use industry-level data to construct an annual country-level measure of external financial dependence and assess its effects on MPK conditional on the level of financial development. Our findings imply that financial development seems to be a necessary condition -and certainly not a sufficient one- in order for production in financially dependent sectors to positively affect aggregate MPK in developing countries. Second, using bilateral FDI inflows in developing countries between 2001 and 2010, we analyze how external financial dependence and financial development determine FDI in flows in developing countries. [...]The third chapter, joint research with Jean-Charles Bricongne and Fabrizio Coricelli, studies the transmission of global shocks during the Great Recession and its impact on French employment. Particularly, we explore the role of trade credit in the propagation of cross-border shocks. Using a sub-sample of importing enterprises that were active over 2004-2009,our findings imply that strong pre-crisis sourcing ties with countries that were more resilient to the global crisis, translated into better performance in terms of employment growth over 2008-2009. This effect dramatically varies with trade credit intensity. Strongly relying on trade credit made firms more vulnerable to unanticipated shocks, for which the adverse impact of the crisis was exacerbated. This effect intensified among firms with important sourcing ties with severely shocked countries. While the negative effect of the crisis was mitigated when sourcing relations with countries subject to milder shocks were stronger. Supporting, therefore, the hypothesis that trade credit was an alternative source of financing for enterprises during the crisis, where implicitly borrowing from suppliers helped importers overcoming financial constraints. Our contribution to the literature adds to the debate on the role of trade finance in explaining the real economic downturn across borders.







Essays in Trade Credit and International Trade


Book Description

When a buyer and a seller meet in the market, both need to decide quantity and price. However, often they also argue when to transfer the payment. In one extreme, the seller may demand early payment before delivering the goods. In the other, the buyer can demand late payment after receiving the products/services. The former is sometimes called cash in advance, while the latter is called trade credit. Understanding the use of trade credit is essential because it is one of the main sources of short-term finance for firms. Additionally, since each trade contract specifies prices, quantities, and payment delay, the contract is implicitly defining who is responsible for financing the production and who bears the risk of default, which can itself be a deterrent to trade. My dissertation aims to study some of the novel factors that shape the use of trade credit and shed some light on its effects on a firm's decision to trade. The first chapter studies the firm-characteristics that shape the use of trade credit decisions in international trade. Trade credit is widely used in firm-to-firm transactions, domestically, and internationally. The literature has found that country-specific features, such as interest rates, legal institutions, the rule of law, and capital controls, affect the decision to extend trade credit. The literature has not studied additional features that might explain the trade credit provision in the international context; it also has not proposed additional theories. To fill this gap, I exploit transaction-level data from Chilean customs. This data set, available for exporters and importers, includes information that describes if a given transaction was paid in advance or paid post-shipment (trade credit). Additionally, I merge this data with firm-level details provided by the Chilean Internal Tax Service. Using this data, I document new facts. Namely, large firms measured by several metrics are most likely to use trade credit compared to small firms. Motivated by these facts and to guide my empirical strategy, I propose a theory for the use of trade credit. The model has the critical assumption that firms, buyer and seller, may default on their contracts due to liquidity shocks. Depending on the size of the shock, the firm can deplete all its assets, which means it will default. This simple assumption will imply that larger firms will be less likely to default since they have enough assets to absorb the liquidity shock. The predictions of the model are confirmed using regression analysis; therefore, not only country-specific attributes but also firm characteristics affect the contract decision: large exporters (importers) are 15% (40%) more likely to sell (buy) under trade credit compared to small exporters (importers). I also find that a small exporter matched with a large importer is 3-10% more likely to sell under trade credit. In the second chapter, we propose a theory for the use of trade credit that connects the markup that the exporter charges to the decision of extending trade credit. The key idea is that under pre-payment, the buyer needs to pay the full amount to the seller before receiving the goods. This payment requires liquidity equal to the total invoice, which in turn corresponds to the production cost plus a markup. In contrast, extending trade credit might be cheaper since the seller only needs to cover its production costs in advance, which is lower than the intermediate price due to the presence of markups. If financial intermediation is costly and the lending interest rate is greater than the deposit rate, then this difference in liquidity needs between pre-payment and trade credit affects profits, affecting the decision to provide trade credit. We test the implications of the theory using Chilean data. First, we construct markup estimates at the firm-product level, using detailed data on inputs and outputs of Chilean plants using the methodology developed by De Loecker, Goldberg, Khandelwal, and Pavcnik (2016). We then use transaction-level Customs data with information on the payment choice to test the model's predictions. We find that trade credit use increases in the markup and that this effect is larger, the bigger the difference between the buyer's borrowing rate and the seller's deposit rate is. the final chapter proposes and tests an alternative theory. Trade credit is used as a quality guarantee. There are two main facts in existing theories that explain the use of trade credit. First, all these theories focus on explaining the extension of trade credit or not, but not the length of the contract. Secondly, and most importantly, some empirical evidence does not speak to these models. Particularly, most of the existing theories conclude that trade credit is used due to access to cheaper credit or as an enforcement mechanism, then restricting the credit period, say to 30 days maximum, should not alter those incentives. However, the finance literature has found that this type of regulation has effects on the economy. Some authors have found that limiting the trade credit period to 30 days has positive effects, from the seller's perspective, through more competition due to the increase in firm entrance and a decrease in exit rates. However, in the same literature, other papers have shown that these laws also have adverse effects, namely, a reduction in the likelihood and volume of trade. The previous evidence indicates that the length of trade credit is also essential to understand the decision and its impact on the firm's behavior. Following Long, Malitz, and Ravid (1993), I propose the theory that trade credit serves as a signal for the quality of the product. In a nutshell, the model assumes that when the quality is not observable, but verifiable ex-post, trade credit can serve as a signal of the product's quality. The logic of the theory is that a buyer will not pay the transaction until she is sure that what she bought is what was agreed upon. Additionally, in this model, trade credit maturity serves a quality guarantee. Longer maturities imply that the buyer has more time to verify the contracted quality. This theory has the main prediction that the provision and maturity of the trade credit are positively related to the quality of the product. To test these predictions, I use a data set from the Chilean Customs. This transaction-level data set has a unique feature: the number of days at which a transaction was paid, on the addition of the usual measures such as destination, price, and quantity. As for quality measures, I will follow two strategies. First, I will use an off-the-shelf methodology that infers quality from prices and quantities, assuming a particular demand elasticity. Secondly, I will focus my attention on a specific industry, wine. For wine, I web-scrapped information of ratings, awards, and retail prices under the assumption that this data captures wine quality. The data confirms the main predictions of the model. I find that high-quality goods are more likely to be sold under trade credit. Moreover, regarding the other predictions, I find that high-quality products have 20 more days of trade credit, out of an average of 100 days.










Doing Business 2020


Book Description

Seventeen in a series of annual reports comparing business regulation in 190 economies, Doing Business 2020 measures aspects of regulation affecting 10 areas of everyday business activity.